Brian Holmes on Thu, 31 May 2001 15:15:23 +0200 (CEST) |
[Date Prev] [Date Next] [Thread Prev] [Thread Next] [Date Index] [Thread Index]
[Nettime-bold] Re: Public Electricity Production |
Ben Moretti's post on industrial planning in South Australia brought this thread toward political economy (my favorite angle). Then Simon Biggs contributed a first-hand recap of the South Australian situation, full of details and insights. Simon wrote: "Arguing that South Australia's wealth was built through a kind of New Deal program centred on housing construction and the centralisation of the means of production (putting various private utility companies into public trust) is to miss the point." The point might be: what did New Deal-type strategies become when they were applied full-scale in the fifties-sixties, in the context of the postwar world-system? I know zip about Australia. I basically just guessed from the description of Thomas Playford that South Australia took up the same centralized planning as most industrial nations after the Second World War, whereby the state orchestrated the growth of complex economies. Simon confirmed that: "...the Leigh Creek coal fields... became the property of the SA Electricity Trust, however whilst much of the power generated was used for the growing cities of the State the key factor in this was the establishment of the steel industry in the three cities of Port Augusta, Whyalla and Port Pirie. Each of these cities was given a role, by the state, in the industry as a whole.... This is a great example of socio-economic engineering, almost Soviet in its scope..." In California where I grew up, the subsidized industries were more diversified, and more research-based than in South Australia: among them were civil aeronautics, a wide range of defense industries, nuclear power, and so on - with labor-intensive agri-business playing a counterpart to the brain-intensive factories. It was at the center of the imperialism that Simon talks about, what radicalized people in those days started calling "the system." But from thirty-forty years distance, you can see how complex that system and its break-up really were. Throughout the industrialized countries, the centrally planned economy had been a regulative response to the crisis of the thirties and the collapse of nineteenth-century liberal capitalism (where the owners really were individuals, and not conglomerates responsible to the state). In the forties, central planning also became a necessity of war, installing the military-industrial complex at the heart of the response to crisis. But then after the destruction and sacrifices, the command economies had to be justified by something more than the need to win. Integrated social and industrial development was the great promise, all around the world. Beyond arguably good things like housing, utilities and basic health care, or what Marxists call "reproduction of the labor force," the state in that period had to provide educational and cultural supplements to the quality of daily life - extensions of consciousness which were necessary for certain aspects of industrial growth. This is where the socio-economic engineering gets interesting, and contradictory. Those educational provisions, which in the large sense could include parks and museums and public TV, were also a vote-winning ploy that could facilitate the deficit spending policy of the time: the old Keynesian trick, using state credit to prime the economic pump. But mass public education is a dangerous good to throw into the mix. It is a more-than-Keynesian multiplier, it doesn't just stimulate economic growth, but opens up new spaces of autonomy. The necessary expansion of education turned out to foster a critique of the state that provided it, and of the bureaucratic rationality that guided technological development. So that the whole complex system that had developed in most industrialized countries after the war began to split itself apart internally - a process exacerbated by the fact that the welfare state brought enormous expenses, and it was getting difficult to politically agree on who should pay. The way the break-up of the system occurred means everything to us today. In some respects, we are still living through a distorted reflection of it. Simon writes: "After the dry and constrained decades of Playford the sense of release and creativity that Dunstan's election brought with it was overpowering. Although I was only a teenager at the time I remember very very well the excitement of the period, as a visceral memory. Ultimately those events shaped my political outlook and that of a generation." The consciousness revolution ran ahead of, and to a certain extent helped provoke the economic crisis. Throughout the world-economy, 1965 to 1973 were the jagged, heady, unpredictable years that closed the long wave of postwar growth, and brought the industrialized countries to a point where Keynesian deficit-spending was no longer practicable. It was a creative time, when individuals could shake off the regimentation that had been the essence of central planning and factory work-discipline. Having gained in rights and entitlements, huge numbers of people found themselves with unexpected agency, and an ambition to derail their little bit of the system - an ambition spurred by the rising awareness of how imperialist and oppressive it really was. That movement was the first to reject the central planners and their entire bureaucratic construction, well before the neoliberals came in to "get the state off our backs." At the same time, the '68 generation pressed for even greater entitlements. Wages rose, bringing inflation; capital interests were threatened and conflicts emerged. Strikes and recession set in to plague the advanced economies in the seventies, and in many places, the machinery of production practically ground to a halt. In the late seventies, under conditions of industrial stagnation and inflation ("stagflation"), no one could see how to get the whole thing rolling again. A new economic paradigm doesn't crystallize all at once, and its transformations are only partially engineered by the elites. What happens is that certain innovations start to dovetail and produce noticeable effects, which are then analyzed, identified, encouraged by other innovations. The first key innovation was financial: with the "monetary turn" in 1979, the US began to float its national debt not through traditional bond issues, which aimed at recycling national savings, but rather through bonds which had been made entirely liquid, turned over to speculation on a volatile world financial market. This not only meant that Japanese investors could now temporarily pay for American spending programs, lessening the political pressure on the executive. Above all it meant that a new niche was created in the world-economy where capital could appreciate in value, rather than depreciating as it did when invested into stagnating, more-or-less state-managed industry. As the paradigm crystallized, the "fictitious" surplus value added in transnational financial markets would increasingly serve as the spark to ignite new production cycles, often across national boundaries, through what is called "foreign direct investment." That's the beginnings of globalization. In retrospect, you can see it as a way of sidestepping the Keynesian use of national tax money for economic planning. Which is also a way of escaping any democratic control over the directions growth would take. Just hang on, we're getting closer to electricity production in 2001. This fundamental change in the way surplus value is reinjected into the system marks a new regulation of the world-economy. But production itself had to change, for the solution to work both politically and industrially. A couple of eggheads named Piore and Sabel make some brilliant remarks in a book called _The Second Industrial Divide_: "The brief moments when the path of industrial development itself is at stake we call industrial divides. At such moments, social conflicts of the most apparently unrelated kinds determine the direction of technological development for the following decades. Although industrialists, workers, politicians and intellectuals may only be dimly aware that they face technological choices, the actions that they take shape economic institutions for long into the future. Industrial divides are therefore the backdrop or frame for subsequent regulation crises." Why did the personal computer, and the associated products from software to media, finally end up at the center of the new "long wave" of growth that followed the recession of the 1970s? My reading is that the personal computer answered the desires of different constituencies within the advanced economies. It helped meet the aspirations of person-to-person communication, spontaneous cooperation and direct democracy that underlay the self-management ideal of the left in the sixties and seventies. But at the same time it was the perfect tool for an emerging, psychologically savvy new managerial elite, globally nomadic and attuned to the split-second fluctuations of the financial markets; and of course, it made the contemporary, world-spanning financial markets possible. The computer sits, or rather spins, at the heart of a production process giving rise to the kinds of symbolic goods that flatter the post-68 emphasis on culture and volatile fashion. But as if by coincidence, these same goods are much more adapted than heavy industrial products to the turnover speed required by the profit-hungry financial markets. The computer permits the labor form that Piore and Sabel call "flexible specialization." As they write: "This strategy is based on flexible - multi-use - equipment; skilled workers; and the creation, through politics, of an industrial community that restricts the forms of competition to those favoring innovation." Toni Negri, Maurizio Lazarrato and the others of that group have brilliantly demonstrated how this kind of cooperative, semi-autonomous labor emerged from the refusal of Fordist productive discipline and welfare-state rationality. And they have gone further, showing how that kind of labor developed, with the information economy, into what they call "mass intellectuality." Most of us on this list are in a version of that bag, I think. Our working style of cooperative cultural/informational production began to take form in the late sixties-early seventies, and actually influenced public policy from the very outset, starting with the Dunstans in Australia or the Jerry Browns in California, and continuing on a vaster level with the Clintons and Blairs today (don't know the Australian equivalents). What I'm trying to get at is that the media-universe of mass intellectuality we are now inhabiting - with its extremely ambiguous stance toward the "public" dimension and towards the role of the state in creating and maintaining it - actually developed most of its discourses and attitudes directly out of the central contradiction I was pointing to before: the contradiction between the economic priorities of central planning and the spaces of autonomy that developed massively in the population, via the entitlements and rights brought by the welfare state. That could sound like another sophisticated bit of useless history, but there's a political point to it. If you want to develop an effective social critique today, if you want to effectively question what's public and what's private, or where technological development is going - if you want, like myself, to help provoke a _new_ regulation crisis that might unseat the domination of the financial markets over the directions of world technological development - you have start by asking this: How has the social formation we are part of, the flexible intellectual laborers, been neutralized? What is it, in the political outlook of a generation that Simon described, that has led to us being so ineffective, after the crisis period around 1965 to 1975? Where, along the path from the welfare state to neoliberalism, did the critical power get lost? And what makes the neoliberal regime, as Beiberger writes in _99 francs_, "the first system of man's domination by man against which even freedom is powerless"? All this was supposed to be about electrical production. Currently the Americans are talking about restarting the enormous industrial program of nuclear power (which, of course, American companies. Westinghouse and GE, never stopped selling outside the US). And Japan is talking about installing solar panels in outer space! It would be absurd to think that this kind of stuff is going to be carried out by the media-happy intellectual laborers of "flexible specialization." But Piore and Sabel point out that flexible specialization was only one side of the response that emerged to the crisis and recession of the seventies. The other strategy "aims at extending the mass-production model. It does so by linking [computer again, BH] the production facilities and markets of the advanced countries with the fastest-growing third-world countries. This response amounts to the use of the corporation (now a multinational entity) to stabilize markets in a world where the forms of cooperation among states [i.e. imperialism, BH] can no longer do the job." Corporate power over technological development, guided by the imperatives of the stock market, and given a legal and diplomatic frame by power groups within the national states which have pulled away from any democratic control (like the executive power we could see operating at the FTAA summit in Quebec). That's what you're facing when you ask the question, What kind of electrical production will we have tomorrow? Will it be public? What does the word public mean? People are finally now asking those kinds of questions again, and using the media tools at their disposal to amplify and intensify their questioning, in the attempt to give it an effective, active place in society. To do that, they have to reevaluate their own attitudes, their own histories. That's the beginnings of the movement of resistance to corporate globalization, or the globalization of capital, as we say here in France. It is like watching a whole social formation wake up from a dream: the dream that you could carry on a public conversation within a space that is almost entirely private - like the Internet, like the American universities, and so on. How to change the architecture of the dream? How to make effective contact with the people exploited and dominated by the corporations, outside the privileged circles of flexible specialization and the media-sphere? How to gain new agency, and exert some control over the transformations? Though I've never been to Australia, nor experienced the power blackouts in California, those are the questions and reflections that the piece on Thomas Playford, the memories of Simon Biggs, and the issue of public electricity production inspire in me. As if we were living in the same world after all. Brian Holmes _______________________________________________ Nettime-bold mailing list Nettime-bold@nettime.org http://www.nettime.org/cgi-bin/mailman/listinfo/nettime-bold