Patrice Riemens on Thu, 14 Aug 2014 17:50:00 +0200 (CEST) |
[Date Prev] [Date Next] [Thread Prev] [Thread Next] [Date Index] [Thread Index]
<nettime> Ippolita Collective, In the Facebook Aquarium, Part III (section 5) |
Ippolita Collective, In the Facebook Aquarium Part III The Freedoms of the Net Mass participation (section 5) The best known instance of mass participation is Wikipedia, the universal encyclopedia numbering now several million entries in dozens of languages, and which is fed by the contributions of millions of volunteers worldwide. It is a astounding experience, and also in many aspects a very innovative one compared to traditional models of collective participation. It is also unique in the sense that as one of the most used and visited websites on the net, it does not finance itself through advertisements, but lives exclusively from donations. But its principal virtue lies in the fact that it puts the emphasis on the non-economic incentives which inspire internauts to collaborate on a project that goes beyond the somewhat musty discourse of the 'gift economy'. One can better call it an economy of attention and recognition. Indeed, what really motivates Wikipedia collaborators, is the acknowledgement they receive from their peers, and the desire they have to see their competence put to use an recognized on a large(r) scale [27]. Nonetheless, numerous elements of criticisms can be levelled against Wikipedia. (Core) Collaborators of the site have started to behave like censors and wish to distinguish themselves from the mass of users (instead of helping them to build up their own role in a creative fashion). Symptoms of hierarchy and domination have appeared within Wikipedia, conflicts have been smouldering among 'wikipedians', and the lore of mass participation is morphing into complex techno-bureaucracies functioning as gate keepers. By now it is essential to 'de-sanctify' the Wikipedia myth: the on-line encyclopedia is _not_ the outcome of the collaboration of human being all united by the same ideal. It is, even in absolute terms, mostly the collaboration between human beings and /bots/. Bots are small programmes performing fully automated tasks (without human intervention). /Rambot/, for instance, created over thirty thousand entries on cities in the world, extracting data from the CIA-published /World Factbook/ and from US civil registries. As of now, bots account for 20% of the Wikipedia entries [28x], bringing forth a highly complex socio-technical phenomenon, on which Bruno Latour, with his 'parliament of things', appears to strike an totally clear and relevant chord [29]. Wikipedia fans or Wikipedia bashers, all must admit that social interaction in these kinds of systems is conducted through programmed and automated protocols. One sees then that sensitive issues, such as the reliability of knowledge, are increasingly entrusted to the care of machines. Then how does the process of unfolding hierarchies work, between reliable and untrustworthy knowledge, and between human and 'mechanical' contributions? Source validation, conflict-avoidance protocol elaboration and common resource allotment allocation are as many urgent issues still awaiting resolution. Taken on the whole, and despite enormous differences, Wikipedia's modus operandi is the same as that of the four giants of the digital world: Facebook, Amazon, Google and Apple. Theirs is the logic of accumulation, of the large numbers and of the power of the masses. Even though they do not broadcast like traditional media they too aspire to hegemony. They compete fiercely among each other because they want to win over a larger public and achieve a higher level of consensus [30]. And as they extol the virtues of the 'long tail' made up of the thousands of individuals for whom mass communication is not good enough, they actually function like aggregators and focus far more on quantity than on quality. Their slogan /mass elitism/ is an oxymoron probably more appropriate than they have bargained for. So, if it is essential to limit the number of participants for a conviviality place to function properly, does that mean that the masses are doomed to content themselves with triviality and live under the compulsion of self-promotion and self-exploitation as a consequence? The author of 'The Wisdom of Crowds', James Surowiecki, disagrees. In his book Surowiecki tries, on an ideological plane, to demonstrate that a randomly chosen (large) group of people together possess more competence than one of a few highly intelligent and well-prepared persons. The idea of the wisdom of crowds is not so much that such a group will always provide a better response, but that, on average, it will (tend to)come up with a better solution than one individual alone would; with other words, a composite crowd is, on average, apt to make better decisions than one expert. We have already said that it was important to discuss the actual role of experts, and even to flip their power back at them. When technical knowledge is exclusively beholden, or outsourced to specialised experts, they quickly loose the ability to realize what their general responsibility entails in the usage that is made of their knowledge power. Every one of them stay on her/his own plot, maintains contact with her/his constituents (clients), and protects her/his own lobby's interests. While at the same time access to knowledge is lost for the citizens/ the common people. Hence, there are necessary conditions to be fulfilled in order for diffuse collective wisdom to express itself: Not all crowds (groups) are wise. Consider, for example, mobs or crazed investors in a stock market bubble. According to Surowiecki, these key criteria separate wise crowds from irrational ones: - Diversity of opinion: Each person should have private information even if it's just an eccentric interpretation of the known facts. - Independence: People's opinions aren't determined by the opinions of those around them. - Decentralisation: People are able to specialize and draw on local knowledge. - Aggregation: Some mechanism exists for turning private judgements into a collective decision. [31] Suriowecki emphasizes the importance of diversity ("as a value in itself"), and of independence, because the best collective decisions are the outcome of disagreement and discussions, not of pre-arranged consensus or compromises. By marshalling very convincing examples, among them the development of the GNU/Linux operating system and the collaboration between laboratories worldwide leading to the discovery of SARS (severe acute respiratory syndrome, or atypical pneumonia), Surowiecki shows that, as paradoxical as it might look given the mental habitus of a majority directed by proxy (of a minority supposed to represent the majority -transl), group intelligence is superior provided that everyone in it acts in the most independent way possible. Individual autonomy is key to a well functioning collective, provided agreement has been reached beforehand on effective rules about sharing and (the) repartition (of tasks). But when one observes the concrete activities of an individual engaging with a (social) network, one sees immediately that decisions-taking is not the only issue at stake. What foremost matters is to enjoy being on a common trajectory, to savour the pleasure of coming together, to explore unknown domains in the creation of common projects, to meet other people, and also simply, to be together in between amicable agreements and the occasional disputes. A crowd becomes only interesting when one comes nearer to it, and discovers the differences which make it up and the personal histories intermingling to form a collective narrative. See from afar, people are mere numbers in statistics, and insignificant dots [32]. Participation is only worthwhile if individuals are into a personal growing-up process. And there is no difference in this between the 'real' and the 'virtual' world. Surowiecki is, again, invaluable to our argument, and this precisely because we do not share at all his exuberant faith in the masses, and neither do we regarding his predilection for business. << Diversity is in fact more important in small groups and in formal organisations than in larger collectives, like markets of electoral constituencies, and this for a very simple reason: most markets, given their size and the fact that anyone with money can enter them ? without need to be either introduced or recruited into them ? means that a minimum level of diversity is always assured. >> [33] The issue of size is hence closely linked to the one about the economy. A long tradition of (human) thought shows that the project called 'economy' (as abstraction), which literally means "rule-norm-law of the house-environment" (and by extension, habitat) as opposed to 'ecology', which is the "discourse on the house-environment-habitat". With other words, a discourse that has the economy as its starting point cannot have social well-being as its aim, even if it pretends the contrary, because the social and the economic are grounded on different premisses. And yet there has been no dearth of attempts, often successful, to win over the practices of social ecology into the economic sphere. A 'new' technology ? or one being presented as such ? which might fulfil some diffuse well-being, works usually as an effective sesame to gain access to available energies (resources) [34] This is in any case the firm belief of the proponents of 'Wikinomy' like Tapscott and Williams, and also of those who go for 'Socialnomics' like Qualman [35]. These new economic and social theories do not longer forefront competition but co-operation. The main idea, depicted as a milestone discovery, being that collaboration produces more added value than competition. Outside the world of business this observation would be considered hackneyed in the extreme, but indeed, in the corporate sphere, it went down like a bomb. Wikinomy then is based on four principles: /openness/, the interaction between peers (meaning an 'autonomous' assemblage of people within the firm); /sharing/ (firms must put their know-how at the disposal of their 'ecosystem' which is made up of clients, suppliers, and partners, so as to foster synergic growth strategies); /global activity/presence/ (no borders}; and /business/, first and last. The most interesting concept in this is that of /openness/ because it evidences the transformation of dynamic ecological equilibrium into economic extraction. It can be seen as the outcome of the neo-liberal capture of the idea of freedom. Just like as in the spicy case of /Open Source/, where the freedom aspect of free software, vexatious to the free marketeers, was quickly transformed into openness, where the firm, which is by tradition a closed shop given to competition, realises its alleged freedom in the form of opening up to the outside. In the same manner, the open society is being hailed as the natural upshot of the libertarian openness of on-line sociality. Firms nowadays have boundaries which are increasingly porous and less and less secure. They outsource, and the strict separation between work and leisure time is waning, not because technology shifts chink time away from work in favour of sociality, but because every moment is now devoted to profit earning. Firms will hand out their employees mobile phones for free, unlimited call plans included, so that they are always reachable, always in touch with each other, and always productive even outside their paid working hours. They are in fact actors on permanent call, but are not acknowledged as such. They are the true slaves of the self-exploitation unleashed by the Wikinomy, automata who seamlessly compose the digital culture's humongous serial work while probably thinking of themselves as the stakeholders in the Net's Collective Intelligence. They then feel compelled to adopt an absurd, totally huxleyan posture, and to participate in the commonwealth by exercising their power as consumers. But if growth is mandatory, it might take little time before not going into debt will be considered immoral, and that calling for de-growth will be taken for a subversive activity. If the masses are so intelligent and so eager to collaborate, then one could imagine that keyboard activism would be a residual phenomenon, and that mass democracy would be just around the corner. But this is not the case, simply because a group does not necessarily function better than a single individual. The sum total of a large number of single, almost undifferentiated (interchangeable) individuals with limited capabilities, not very prone to engage in discussions, and with little time at their disposal to contribute to the building of a common world, will for sure generate a great number of clicks on advertisement banners, but will not end up into collective participation as a source of great hopes. Much longer before Silicon Valley got a crunch on the wisdom of crowds, psychologists had found out that the performance of individuals in and as a group could be less than when they were working on their own. Synergy is not a conditioned response. In 1882, the French agronomist Maximilien Ringelmann conducted the following experiment in the field - literaly: four people were asked to pull on a rope, firstly all together, then one after the other, with the rope being attached to a dynamometer (to measure the force of traction). Ringelmann was surprised to discover that the sum total of the individually exercised pulls was significantly higher than that of the group. Many more studies have confirmed this 'Ringelmann effect', and have shown that people will generally devote less efforts to a task when accomplished together with others. This non-synergic effect is the most notable with simple, repetitive tasks, in which every link in the chain has a possibly important role to play, yet can be taken by anyone indiscriminately: to clap at the theatre venue, to vote, to click on 'Like', etc. When individual differences are not highlighted, an increase in the number of participants often results in results going from bad to worse as the peer pressure diminishes together with (the appreciation of) distinctive characteristics. Why should we commit ourselves and go the extra mile if anyone can click 'Like' in our stead? It is not advisable to try to distinguish oneself in a mass since the identity of group is based on homology, not on exception. To put it tritely, an atomised individual, permanently taught to be as interchangeable as possible with any other 'atom', must develop 'standard' characteristics so as to be attractive in the global market, in an endless repetition of the identical, with minimal variations already pre-formated by the profiling system. Conversely, an autonomous individual will be the more interesting because sHe is unique, endowed with specific characteristics, and so becomes a mixture of various ingredients and experiences which are (well-nigh) impossible to reproduce. It is reasonable to think that such an individual will join various groups, not for the sake of self-promotion, but for the pleasure of sharing and meeting with other, like-minded individuals. To belong to a community, to an organized network functioning like a 'we' means to feel represented, not because one has the right of veto or of vote, but because one has a direct influence on the network, because one can have influence on others and in turn be influenced by them. One swaps experiences and make changes happen by building a common history together. This is a necessarily complex and dynamic equilibrium where mutual limits and boundaries are constantly (re)negotiated. It is not possible to imagine (the existence/ possibility of) once and for all formatted individuals, shaped by stringent parameters, as are the (virtual) actors of the (idealised) libertarian market, acting in perfectly and totally pre-programmed groups, and sticking to the letter to a manifesto or a letter of intent. On the other hand, even an individual's most extraordinary (weird?) competences need to find a way to blend within an organised network, as the mere fact of not to be part of a mass does not mean diminishing control. On the contrary, control at the minute level also exists in small group, and in is even in these that it is at its most intense. One person's error can cause the fall of all. The discontent of the one can infect all others, conflicts then can grow out of proportions sickening and blacking out any positive vision. There is however, a big difference between control managed by automatic systems with profit as motive, as in the case of mass profiling, and the mutual control exercised by members of a small group. The ties which make the network emerge within a group build up around everyone's affinity are also trust relationships. One knows one can rely one others' opinion and use the group as a sounding board. Social control can then also function as a guarantee for individual autonomy, especially in times of despondency and fatigue, when an individual is no longer very clear-headed and start behaving funny, boring, our outright destructive/aggressive. As keepers of a shared history, and thus also our own history, the others are the ones who can remind us that we not always been suffering and in despair. And that in the past we have made major contributions and that there is no reason why we will not do so in the future. Attention and recognition is the currency that circulates in an organised network. It is the time that we spend to weave these ties, either in full measure, or at least as a principal and privileged activity, which makes the experience priceless. (to be continued) next time: Beyond technophobia: let's build convivial technologies (section 6) ------------------------------ [31] Quoted from the Wikipedia entry on The Wisdom of Crowds: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/The_Wisdom_of_Crowds after James Surowiecki, /The Wisdom of Crowds: Why the Many Are Smarter Than the Few and How Collective Wisdom Shapes Business, Economies, Societies and Nations/ NYC, Doubleday, Anchor, 2004 [32] We may refer here to the famous words spoken by Orson Welles and Joseph Cotten on the value of human life, atop the Ferris wheel in Vienna Prater amusement park in Carol Reeds memorable film /The Third Man/ (1949). Looking down on the people below from his vantage point, Lime (Orson Welles) compares them to dots, and says that it would be insignificant if one of them or a few of them "stopped moving, forever". http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/The_Third_Man http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/The_Third_Man#The_.22Swiss_cuckoo_clock.22_speech [33] James Surowiecki, /op. Cit./ p ...? (the quote is (re-)translated from the book since I have no access to the original, and the passage did not feature in the GoogleBooks excerpts: http://bit.ly/1oGB1ue [34] A good overview of the ambiguity prevailing with respect to technology and social ecology is provided by Murray Bookchin's book /The Ecology of Freedom: The Emergence and Dissolution of Hierarchy/ Palo Alto, Cheshire Books, 1982, especially Chapters IX and X on 'Two Images of Technology' and on the 'Social Matrix of Technology'. Bookchin's book is downloadable in its entirety on several sites, like: http://kickass.to/the-ecology-of-freedom-murray-bookchin-pdf-t8060106.html or http://alotof.org/w/File:Murray_Bookchin_The_Ecology_of_Freedom_1982.pdf [35] Don Tapscott, Anthony D Williams, /Wikinomics: /How Mass Collaboration Changes Everything/ Portfolio, 2006: http://www.wikinomics.com/book/ Even more 'disrupting' is Erik Qualman's /Socialnomics: How Social Media Transform the Way We Live and Do Business, NYC, Wiley, 2009. GoogleBooks excerpts at: http://bit.ly/1yroDUA ----------------------------- Translated by Patrice Riemens This translation project is supported and facilitated by: The Institute of Network Cultures, Amsterdam University of Applied Sciences (http://networkcultures.org/wpmu/portal/) The Antenna Foundation, Nijmegen (http://www.antenna.nl - Dutch site) (http://www.antenna.nl/indexeng.html - english site under construction) Casa Nostra, Vogogna-Ossola, Italy # distributed via <nettime>: no commercial use without permission # <nettime> is a moderated mailing list for net criticism, # collaborative text filtering and cultural politics of the nets # more info: http://mx.kein.org/mailman/listinfo/nettime-l # archive: http://www.nettime.org contact: nettime@kein.org